Suppose that we can find the solution of the PDE, say G(w, ν, τ ), with the property that at t = T , G(w, ν, 0) = 1. Then the solution to the transformed PDE {48} with payoff condition U (w, ν, 0) is just the product of this with G.
(49)
Lewis (refer to [11]) discusses how to solve {49} for the general case, but here we will only solve for the Heston model (γ = 1/ 2 ).
Greeks for free
Before figuring out G, we should point out that {49} is a remarkably useful representation. If you want to differentiate V with respect to S to obtain ∆, you merely multiply the integral by:
and for Γ, the integral is multiplied by:
This representation also makes obvious the link between ρ and ∆.
Finding the fundamental solution
For γ = 1/ 2 and Heston parameters, the PDE {48} yield the form:
(50)
What Heston [6] does is try to find a solution in the form:
with:
A [0, w] = B [0, w] = 0
in order to satisfy the condition that G[0, w] = 1 (at maturity). If we substitute this assumption for the form of G into the PDE {50}, we obtain the following condition:
The A' and B' denote the τ − derivative. This must be true for all ν so we separately equate the terms that are independent of ν and linear in ν to obtain the pair of ordinary differential equations:
Solving this, we obtain:
where:
So the exact solution of the option price using Heston volatility is:
(51)
using the condition:
for
Call options Im(w) > 1
Put options Im(w) < 0
For further information or more details, see [16] or [6].
Prof. Klaus Schmitz
Next: Derivation of the 2D Milstein Scheme
Summary: Index